World Library  
Flag as Inappropriate
Email this Article

Dividend discount model

Article Id: WHEBN0015773113
Reproduction Date:

Title: Dividend discount model  
Author: World Heritage Encyclopedia
Language: English
Subject: T-model, Valuation (finance), Residual income valuation, Financial statement analysis, Trade (financial instrument)
Collection: Finance Theories, Financial Terminology, Valuation (Finance)
Publisher: World Heritage Encyclopedia
Publication
Date:
 

Dividend discount model

The dividend discount model (DDM) is a method of valuing a company's stock price based on the theory that its stock is worth the sum of all of its future dividend payments, discounted back to their present value.[1] In other words, it is used to value stocks based on the net present value of the future dividends. The equation most widely used is called the Gordon growth model. It is named after Myron J. Gordon of the University of Toronto, who originally published it along with Eli Shapiro in 1956 and made reference to it in 1959.[2][3] Their work borrowed heavily from the theoretical and mathematical ideas found in John Burr Williams 1938 book "The Theory of Investment Value."

The variables are: P is the current stock price. g is the constant growth rate in perpetuity expected for the dividends. r is the constant cost of equity capital for that company. D_1 is the value of the next year's dividends.

P = \frac{D_1}{r-g}

Contents

  • Derivation of equation 1
  • Income plus capital gains equals total return 2
  • Growth cannot exceed cost of equity 3
  • Some properties of the model 4
  • Problems with the model 5
  • Related methods 6
  • References 7
  • Further reading 8
  • External links 9

Derivation of equation

The model uses the fact that the current value of the dividend payment D_0 (1+g)^t at (discrete ) time t is \frac{D_0 (1+g)^t}{(1+r)^t}

This summation can be rewritten as

P={D_0} r' (1+r'+{r'}^2+{r'}^3+....)

where

r'=\frac{(1+g)}{(1+r)}.

Clearly, the series in parenthesis is the geometric series with common ratio r' so it sums to \frac{1}{1-r'} if r'<1. Thus,

P = \frac{D_0 r'}{1-r'}

Substituting the value for r' leads to

P = \frac {\frac{1-\frac{1+g}{1+r}},

which is simplified by multiplying by \frac {1+r}{1+r}, so that

P = \frac{D_0(1+g)}{r-g}

Income plus capital gains equals total return

The equation can also be understood to compute the value of a stock such that the sum of its dividend yield (income) plus its growth (capital gains) equals the investor's required total return. Consider the dividend growth rate as a proxy for the growth of earnings and by extension the stock price and capital gains. Consider the company's cost of equity capital as a proxy for the investor's required total return.[4]

\text{Income} + \text{Capital Gain} = \text{Total Return}
\text{Dividend Yield} + \text{Growth} = \text{Cost Of Equity}
\frac{D}{P} + g = r
\frac{D}{P} = r - g
\frac{D}{r -g} = P

Growth cannot exceed cost of equity

From the first equation, one might notice that r-g cannot be negative. When growth is expected to exceed the cost of equity in the short run, then usually a two-stage DDM is used:

P = \sum_{t=1}^N \frac{D_0 \left( 1+g \right)^t}{\left( 1+r\right)^t} + \frac{P_N}{\left( 1 +r\right)^N}

Therefore,

P = \frac{D_0 \left( 1 + g \right)}{r-g} \left[ 1- \frac{\left( 1+g \right)^N}{\left( 1 + r \right)^N} \right] + \frac{D_0 \left( 1 + g \right)^N \left( 1 + g_\infty \right)}{\left( 1 + r \right)^N \left( r - g_\infty \right)},

where g denotes the short-run expected growth rate, g_\infty denotes the long-run growth rate, and N is the period (number of years), over which the short-run growth rate is applied.

Even when g is very close to r, P approaches infinity, so the model becomes meaningless.

Some properties of the model

a) When the growth g is zero the dividend is capitalized.

P_0 = \frac{D_1}{r}.

b) This equation is also used to estimate cost of capital by solving for r.

r = \frac{D_1}{P_0} + g.

Problems with the model

a) The presumption of a steady and perpetual growth rate less than the cost of capital may not be reasonable.

b) If the stock does not currently pay a dividend, like many growth stocks, more general versions of the discounted dividend model must be used to value the stock. One common technique is to assume that the Modigliani-Miller hypothesis of dividend irrelevance is true, and therefore replace the stocks's dividend D with E earnings per share. However, this requires the use of earnings growth rather than dividend growth, which might be different. This approach is especially useful for computing a residual value of future periods.

c) The stock price resulting from the Gordon model is hyper-sensitive to the growth rate g chosen.

Related methods

The dividend discount model is closely related to both discounted earnings and discounted cashflow models. In either of the latter two, the value of a company is based on how much money is made by the company. For example, if a company consistently paid out 50% of earnings as dividends, then the discounted dividends would be worth 50% of the discounted earnings. Also, in the dividend discount model, a company that does not pay dividends is worth nothing.

References

  1. ^ Investopedia – Digging Into The Dividend Discount Model
  2. ^ Gordon, M.J and Eli Shapiro (1956) "Capital Equipment Analysis: The Required Rate of Profit," Management Science, 3,(1) (October 1956) 102-110. Reprinted in Management of Corporate Capital, Glencoe, Ill.: Free Press of, 1959.
  3. ^
  4. ^ Spreadsheet for variable inputs to Gordon Model

Further reading

External links

  • Alternative derivations of the Gordon Model and its place in the context of other DCF-based shortcuts
This article was sourced from Creative Commons Attribution-ShareAlike License; additional terms may apply. World Heritage Encyclopedia content is assembled from numerous content providers, Open Access Publishing, and in compliance with The Fair Access to Science and Technology Research Act (FASTR), Wikimedia Foundation, Inc., Public Library of Science, The Encyclopedia of Life, Open Book Publishers (OBP), PubMed, U.S. National Library of Medicine, National Center for Biotechnology Information, U.S. National Library of Medicine, National Institutes of Health (NIH), U.S. Department of Health & Human Services, and USA.gov, which sources content from all federal, state, local, tribal, and territorial government publication portals (.gov, .mil, .edu). Funding for USA.gov and content contributors is made possible from the U.S. Congress, E-Government Act of 2002.
 
Crowd sourced content that is contributed to World Heritage Encyclopedia is peer reviewed and edited by our editorial staff to ensure quality scholarly research articles.
 
By using this site, you agree to the Terms of Use and Privacy Policy. World Heritage Encyclopedia™ is a registered trademark of the World Public Library Association, a non-profit organization.
 


Copyright © World Library Foundation. All rights reserved. eBooks from Project Gutenberg are sponsored by the World Library Foundation,
a 501c(4) Member's Support Non-Profit Organization, and is NOT affiliated with any governmental agency or department.